Introduction


Early Developments
In 1900, French mathematician Louis Bachelier published his PhD thesis, Théorie de la Spéculation (Theory of Speculation) (Bachelier, 1900). He recognized that “past, present and even discounted future events are reflected in market price, but often show no apparent relation to price changes”. Hence, the market does not predict changes in asset prices. Moreover, he deduced that ‘The mathematical expectation of the speculator is zero’, which is consistent with Samuelson (1965) in explaining efficient markets in terms of a martingale. The implication is that asset prices fluctuate randomly, and then their movements are not predictable.
Pearson (1905) introduced the term ‘random walk’ to describe the path taken by a drunk with the drunk staggering in an unpredictable and random pattern. If prices follow a random walk, then it is difficult to predict the future path of asset prices. Kendall (1953), in examining weekly data on stock prices finds that they essentially move in a random walk pattern with near-zero autocorrelation of price changes. Working (1934) and Roberts (1959) find that the movements of stock prices look like a random walk. Cowles (1933 and 1944) and Working (1949) document that market participants cannot successfully forecast, and investors cannot beat the market.
Recent Developments
Eugene Fama, the Nobel laureate in 2013, made influential contributions to theoretical and empirical investigation for the recent development of market efficiency. Fama (1965a) defines an efficient market as a market in which there are a lot of rational, profit-maximizing, actively competing traders, who try to predict future asset values with current available information. In an efficient market, competition among many sophisticated traders leads to a situation where actual asset prices, at any point in time, already reflect the effects of all available information and therefore, they will be good estimates of their intrinsic values. The intrinsic value of an asset depends upon the earnings prospects of the company under study, which is not known exactly in an uncertain world, so that its actual price is expected to be above or below its intrinsic value. If the number of the competing traders is large enough, their actions should cause the actual asset price to wander randomly about its intrinsic value through offsetting mechanisms in the markets, and the resulting successive price changes will be independent. A market in which the prices of securities change independently of each other is defined as a random-walk market (Fama, 1965a). Fama (1965b) links the random walk theory to the empirical study on market efficiency. The theory of random walk requires successive prices changes to be independent and to follow some probability distribution.
When the flow of news coming into the market is random and unpredictable, current price changes will reflect only current news and will be independent of past price changes. Hence, independence of successive price changes implies that the history of an asset price cannot help in predicting its future prices and profits. It is then consistent with the existence of an efficient market. Using serial correlation tests, run tests and Alexander’s (1961) filter technique, Fama (1965b) cannot reject the independence of successive price changes and concludes that history of price changes would not help make the expected profits of market traders more than buy-and-hold.
The random-walk theory does not specify the shape of the probability distribution of price changes. Fama (1965b) finds that a Paretian distribution with characteristic exponents less than 2 fit the stock market data better than the Gaussian distribution, which is in line with the findings of Mandelbrot (1963). Hence, the empirical distributions have more relative frequency in their extreme tails than would be expected under a Gaussian distribution while the intrinsic values change by large amounts during very short periods of time.
Efficient-market Hypothesis (EMH)
A comprehensive review of theory and evidence on market efficiency was first provided by Fama (1970). He defines an efficient market in which asset prices at any time fully reflect all available information, and then further introduces three kinds of tests of EMH that are concerned with different sets of relevant information.
Weak form tests
Weak-form tests are used to examine whether investors can earn abnormal profits from the past data on asset prices. If successive price changes are independent and then unpredictable, it is impossible for investors to earn more than buy-and-hold. In literature, there is evidence of random walk and independence in the successive price changes in support of weak-form market efficiency (e.g., Alexander, 1961; Fama, 1965a, b; Fama and Blume, 1966).
Nevertheless, Fama (1970) recognizes that rejection of the random walk model does not imply market inefficiency. Market efficiency does not require the independence assumption, which is too restrictive, but only requires the martingale process of asset returns (Samuelson, 1965) with zero expected profits to the investors. Guo, Jiang, and Wong (2017) show that stochastic dominance and Omega ratio can be used to examine whether the market is efficient while Bai, Li, Liu, and Wong (2011), Bai, Li, McAleer, and Wong (2015), Ng, Wong, and Xiao, (2017), and Chan, Clark, Guo, and Wong (2020) have developed statistics that can be used to test for market efficiency. There are many applications to examine whether the market is efficient, see, for example, Lean, McAleer, and Wong (2010), Chan, De Peretti, Qiao, and Wong (2012), Tsang, Wong, and Horowitz (2016), Zhu, Bai, Vieito, and Wong (2019), Woo, Mai, McAleer, and Wong (2020), Wong (2020, 2021), Hon, Moslehpour, and Woo (2021), Lv, Tsang, Wagner, and Wong (2022), Chan, Chow, Guo, and Wong (2022), Wong, Yeung, and Lu (2022), Lakshmi (2022), Archer, Owusu Junior, Adam, Asafo-Adjei, and Baffoe (2022), Wong, Broll, Qiao, and Ma (2023), and many others. Furthermore, if investors can make significant abnormal profits using any tools in technical analysis based on past data, the weak-form efficiency is also violated. For instance, Wong, Chew, and Sikorski (2001), Wong, Manzur, and Chew (2003), Lam, Chong, and Wong (2007), McAleer, Suen, and Wong (2016) and Chong, Cao, and Wong (2017) propose new trading rules or indicators to earn abnormal profits in the markets. However, Kung and Wong (2009 a, b) find that the use of trading rule in technical analysis may have been useful in the past but may not be able to generate significant profit currently.
Semi-strong form tests
Semi-strong form tests involve an event study which is used to test the adjustment speed of asset prices in response to an event announcement released to the public. An event study averages the cumulative abnormal return of assets under investigation over time, from a specified number of pre-event time periods to a specified number of post-event periods. Fama, Fisher, Jensen, and Roll (1969) provide evidence on the reaction of share prices to stock split in support of semi-strong form market efficiency. Other event studies on earnings announcements (Ball and Brown, 1968), announcements of discount rate changes (Waud, 1970) and secondary offerings of common stocks (Scholes, 1972) generally provide supportive evidence for semi-strong forms of market efficiency.
Strong-form Tests
Strong-form tests are used to assess whether professional investors have monopolistic access to all private as well as public information so that they can outperform the market. Jensen (1968) indicates that professional investors of mutual funds cannot beat the market in favor of the strong-form market efficiency. Malkiel (2005) also finds that the performance of professional investment managers in domestic and foreign capital markets does not exceed the corresponding index benchmark so that market prices already reflect all available public and inside information.
Evolution of EMH
Besides market risk that exists in tradition asset pricing models, some propose additional risk factors in factor models to explain cross-section expected returns of securities, so the excess returns are considered as compensations for additional sources of risk (Beard and Sias, 1997; Fama and French, 2008).
Fama-French Three-Factor Model
Fama and French (1993) provide evidence that a three-factor model can explain stock returns. The three-factor model considers that the excess returns of a stock portfolio can be explained by its exposure to three factors: market risk premium (RMRF), market value factor (SMB, Small market capitalization Minus Big market capitalization), and book-to-market ratio factor (HML, High book-to-market ratio Minus Low book-to-market ratio).
Carhart Four-Factor Model
Some factors, like short-term reversal, medium-term momentum, volatility, skewness, gambling, and others are not considered or included in the three-factor model. Carhart (1997) develops a four-factor model which includes the momentum factor (PRIYR, the return for the one-year momentum in stock returns) in addition to RMRF, SMB and HML. Carhart (1997) provides evidence that it can explain large cross-sectional variation of the average returns stock portfolios.
Fama-French Five-Factor Asset Pricing Model
Fama and French (2015) further examine profitability and investment factors, as well as RMRF, SMB and HML, which is called a five-factor asset pricing model, to absorb the patterns in average returns and explain more anomalies. Fama and French (2017) tested the five-factor model. They found that average stock returns for markets of North America, Europe, and Asia Pacific increase with HML and profitability factor and are negatively related to the investment factor. The relation between average returns for the market of Japan and HML is strong but there is little relation between average returns and profitability or investment factor.
Liu-Stambaugh-Yuan Factor Models
Liu, Stambaugh and Yuan (2019) propose a Chinese version of the three-factor model which consists of EP (earning-price ratio) as well as RMRF and SMB, of the four-factor model which consists of turnover factor PMO (Pessimistic minus Optimistic) as well as EP, RMRF and SMB, and of the seven-factor model which consists of trading volume and turnover rate factors in addition to RMRF, SMB, HML, profitability and investment factors. These Chinese versions of factor models can empirically explain the returns on China’s A-share market. Bian, McAleer, and Wong (2013) develop a modified maximum likelihood (MML) estimator for the multiple linear regression model with underlying student t distribution and demonstrate that the MML estimator is more appropriate for estimating the parameters of the Capital Asset Pricing Model. This approach could also be used to get better estimations for all the factor models, including Fama-French Three-Factor Model, Carhart Four-Factor Model, Fama-French Five-Factor Asset Pricing Model, Liu-Stambaugh-Yuan Factor Models, and others.
References
Alexander, Sidney S. 1961. Price Movements in Speculative Markets: Trends or Random Walks. Industrial Management Review 2(2): 7–26.
Archer, Christina, Peterson Owusu Junior, Anokye M. Adam, Emmanuel Asafo-Adjei, and Stephen Baffoe. 2022. Asymmetric Dependence between Exchange Rate and Commodity Prices in Ghana. Annals of Financial Economics 17(2): 2250012.
Bachelier, Louis. 1900. Theory of Speculation. Edited by Paul H. Cootner. 1964. The Random Character of Stock Market Prices. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 17-78.
Bai, Zhidong, Hua Li, Michael McAleer, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2015. Stochastic dominance statistics for risk averters and risk seekers: An analysis of stock preferences for USA and China. Quantitative Finance 15(5): 889-900.
Bai, Zhidong, Hua Li, Huixia Liu, and Wing‐Keung Wong. 2011. Test Statistics for Prospect and Markowitz Stochastic Dominances with Applications. The Econometrics Journal 14(2): 278-303.
Bian, Guorui, Michael McAleer, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2013. Robust Estimation and Forecasting of the Capital Asset Pricing Model. Annals of Financial Economics 8(2): 1350007.
Ball, Ray, and Philip Brown. 1968. An Empirical Evaluation of Accounting Income Numbers. Journal of Accounting Research 6: 159-178.
Beard, Craig G., and Richard W. Sias 1997. Is There a Neglected-Firm Effect? Financial Analysts Journal, 53(5): 19-23.
Carhart, Mark M. 1997. On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance. Journal of Finance 52(1): 57-82.
Chan, Chia-Ying, Christian De Peretti, Zhuo Qiao, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2012. Empirical Test of the Efficiency of the UK Covered Warrants Market: Stochastic Dominance and Likelihood Ratio Test Approach. Journal of Empirical Finance 19(1): 162-174.
Chan, Raymond H., Sheung-Chi Chow, Xu Guo, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2022. Central Moments, Stochastic Dominance, Moment Rule, and Diversification with an Application.” Chaos, Solitons & Fractals 161: 112251.
Chan, Raymond H., Ephraim Clark, Xu Guo, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2020. New Development on the Third-order Stochastic Dominance for Risk-averse and Risk-seeking investors with Application in Risk Management. Risk Management 22: 108-132.
Chong, Terence Tai-Leung, Bingqing Cao, Wing-Keung Wong. 2017, A Principal Component Approach to Measuring Investor Sentiment in Hong Kong, Journal of Management Sciences 4: 237-247.
Cowles, Alfred 1933. Can Stock Market Forecasters Forecast? Econometrica 1: 309–324.
Cowles, Alfred 1944. Stock Market Forecasting. Econometrica 12: 206–214.
Fama, Eugene F. 1965a. Random Walks in Stock Market Prices. Financial Analysts Journal 51(1):75-80.
Fama, Eugene F. 1965b. The Behavior of Stock-Market Prices. Journal of Business 38(1): 34–105.
Fama, Eugene F. 1970. Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work. Journal of Finance 25(2): 383–417.
Fama, Eugene F. 1991. Efficient Capital Markets II. Journal of Finance 46(5), 1575-1617
Fama, Eugene F. and Marshall E. Blume. 1966. Filter Rules and Stock Market Trading. Journal of Business 39(1): 226-241.
Fama, Eugene F., Lawrence Fisher, J Michael C. Jensen, and Richard Roll. 1969. The Adjustment of Stock Prices to New Information. International Economic Review 10(1): 1-21.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1993. Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33(1): 3-56.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 2008. Dissecting Anomalies. Journal of Finance 63(4): 1653-1678.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 2015. A Five-Factor Asset Pricing Model. Journal of Financial Economics 116(1): 1-22.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 2017. International Tests of a Five-Factor Asset Pricing Model. Journal of Financial Economics 123(3): 441-463.
Grossman, Sanford J., and Joseph E. Stiglitz, 1980. On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets. American Economic Review, 70(3),393–408.
Guo, Xu, Xuejun Jiang, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2017. Stochastic Dominance and Omega Ratio: Measures to Examine Market Efficiency, Arbitrage Opportunity, and Anomaly. Economies 5(4): 38.
Hon, Tai-Yuen, Massoud Moslehpour, and Kai-Yin Woo. 2021. Review on Behavioral Finance with Empirical Evidence. Advances in Decision Sciences 25(4): 1-30.
Jensen, Michael C. 1968. The Performance of Mutual Funds in the Period 1945-64, Journal of Finance 23(2): 389-416.
Kendall, M. G., and A. Bradford Hill. 1953. The Analysis of Economic Time-Series-Part I: Prices. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. 116: 11–34.
Kung, James J., and Wing-Keung Wong. 2009a. Profitability of Technical Analysis in Singapore Stock Market: Before and After the Asian Financial Crisis. Journal of Economic Integration 24: 133-150.
Kung, James J., and Wing-Keung Wong. 2009b. Efficiency of the Taiwan Stock Market. Japanese Economic Review 60: 389-394.
Lakshmi, V. D. M. V. 2022. Do Exchange Traded Funds in India Have Tracking and Pricing Efficiency? Advances in Decision Sciences, 26(2), 1-25.
Lam, Vincent Wing-Shing, Terence Tai-Leung Chong and Wing-Keung Wong. 2007. Profitability of Intraday and Interday Momentum Strategies. Applied Economics Letters 14(15): 1103–1108.
Lean, Hooi Hooi, Michael McAleer, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2010. Market Efficiency of Oil Spot and Futures: A Mean-variance and Stochastic Dominance Approach. Energy Economics 32(5): 979-986.
Liu, Jianan, Robert F. Stambaugh, and Yu Yuan. 2019. Size and Value in China. Journal of Financial Economics 134: 48-69.
Lv, Zhihui, Chun-Kei Tsang, Niklas F. Wagner, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2022. What is an Optimal Allocation in Hong Kong Stock, Real Estate, and Money Markets: An Individual Asset, Efficient Frontier Portfolios, or a Naïve Portfolio? Is This a New Financial Anomaly? Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 1-18.
Malkiel, Burton G. 2005. Reflections on the Efficient Markets Hypothesis 30 years Later. The Financial Review, 40(1), 1-9.
Mandelbrot, Benoît B. 1963. The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices. Journal of Business 36(4): 394-419.
McAleer, Michael, John Suen, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2016, Profiteering from the Dot-com Bubble, Subprime Crisis and Asian Financial Crisis. Japanese Economic Review 67: 257-279.
Pearson, Karl. 1905. The Problem of the Random Walk. Nature 72(1866): 318-319.
Ng, Pin, Wing-Keung Wong, and Zhijie Xiao. 2017. Stochastic dominance via quantile regression with applications to investigate arbitrage opportunity and market efficiency. European Journal of Operational Research 261(2): 666-678.
Rubinstein, Mark 2001. Rational Markets: Yes or No? The Affirmative Case. Financial Analysts Journal, 57(3), 15–29.
Roberts, Harry V. 1959. Stock Market “Patterns” and Financial Analysis: Methodological Suggestions. Journal of Finance, 14: 1-10
Samuelson, Paul A. 1965. Proof that Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly. Industrial Management Review 6: 41–49.
Scholes, Myron S. 1972. The Market for Securities: Substitution versus Price Pressure and the Effects of Information on Share Prices. Journal of Business 45: 179–211.
Tsang, Chun-Kei, Wing-Keung Wong, and Ira Horowitz. 2016. Arbitrage Opportunities, Efficiency, and the Role of Risk Preferences in the Hong Kong Property Market. Studies in Economics and Finance 33(4): 735-754.
Waud, Roger N. 1970. Public Interpretation of Discount Rate Changes: Evidence on the ‘Announcement Effect’. Econometrica 38: 231–50.
Wong, Wing-Keung. 2020. Review on Behavioral Economics and Behavioral Finance, Studies in Economics and Finance 37(4), 625-672. https://doi.org/10.1108/SEF-10-2019-0393
Wong, Wing-Keung. 2021. Editorial Statement and Research Ideas for Behavioral Financial Economics in the Emerging Market.” International Journal of Emerging Markets 16(5): 946-951.
Wong, Wing-Keung, Udo Broll, Zhuo Qiao, Chenghu Ma, 2023. New Stochastic Dominance Theory for Investors with Risk-averse and Risk-seeking Utilities with Applications. Risk Management, forthcoming.
Wong, Wing-Keung, Boon-Kiat Chew and Douglas Sikorski. 2001. Can P/E Ratio and Bond Yield be used to Beat Stock Markets? Multinational Finance Journal 5(1): 59-86.
Wong, Wing-Keung, Meher Manzur and Boon-Kiat Chew. 2003. How Rewarding is Technical Analysis? Evidence from Singapore Stock Market. Applied Financial Economics 13(7): 543-551.
Wong, Wing-Keung, David Yeung, and Richard Lu. 2022. The Mean-variance Rule for Investors with Reverse S-shaped Utility. Annals of Financial Economics 2250030.
Woo, Kai-Yin, Chulin Mai, Michael McAleer, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2020. Review on Efficiency and Anomalies in Stock Markets. Economies, 8(1), 20.
Working, Holbrook. 1934. A Random-Difference Series for use in the Analysis of Time Series. Journal of the American Statistical Association 29(185): 11-24.
Working, Holbrook. 1949. The Investigation of Economic Expectations. American Economic Review 39(3): 150–166.
Zhu, Zhenzhen, Zhidong Bai, João Paulo Vieito, and Wing‐Keung Wong. 2019. The impact of the Global Financial Crisis on the Efficiency and Performance of Latin American Stock Markets. Estudios de Economía 46(1).